In concentrating on these three areas, they seem to preclude an obvious and overriding observation: that trade interdependence has a pivotal impact on how willing people are to centralise power to the state a necessary precondition to inclusive political institutions , and critically affects the manner in which that power is exercised. For example, if societal groups have an enduring and preeminent loyalty to only their immediate group, which may be limited for a multitude of reasons geographic isolation, scarcity of resources , it is unlikely they will be willing or able collectively to centralise power alongside other isolated groups.
Countries that consist of hundreds of such groups abound, especially in the Pacific. Unless and until interaction between these groups is frequent and mutually fruitful trade interdependence , centralisation of political power is unlikely.
Accountability the manner in which centralised power is exercised , is also affected by trade interdependence. If a particular isolated, self-sufficient group gains power over several isolated neighbouring groups, it is likely the powerful group will establish extractive institutions that benefit only themselves. As they do not interact frequently with or depend on the other groups, they are not accountable to them.
The vicious cycle is guaranteed at the outset, given the lack of interdependence and lack of accountability. The converse of this isolation is the concentration of several different groups that do not face such barriers to interaction, and that rely on trade with each other. Conjure a country rich in resources with several distinct groups that rely on trade with each other. Those on the coast would trade aquaculture products for resources produced by those inland, perhaps timber or stone.
Given sufficient time, the economies of the separate groups would become intertwined, interdependent. It would be in the interest of any political authority to serve both their immediate group and those they trade with, as otherwise the valuable resources your group has come to rely on would be at risk.
Inclusive institutions are far more likely to emerge under this scenario. As with the cultural example, intranational geographic isolation makes for a more suspicious peoples who are unwilling to centralise power. However, there is also the issue of geographic factors on the international scale.
The prevalence of domesticable livestock, arable land, and plants that are able to be harvested make critical differences in the productivity of a people. For example, the lack of horse, cattle, sheep, wheat, and barley in your country, no matter how altruistic and centralised your political systems are, will leave you at a disadvantage compared to a nation that has access to these resources.
Higher productivity leads to more time dedicated to other pursuits inventing, writing, thinking, creating permanent settlements.
The importance of the absence of these resources is unduly discounted in the book. Finally comes what can be deduced from the discussion, even if unintended. The authors have attempted to explain historically why nations have failed. In their thesis they rightly dismiss the factors of culture and ignorance, and discount the importance of trade interdependence and geography.
The modern world, however, is far less constrained by these limitations — livestock and crops can be grown around the world, thanks to irrigation, people are able to travel to any number of nations, and global trade is indispensably intertwined. This largely removes these limitations. So although Acemoglu and Robinson have attempted to explain the historical reasons nations have failed in the past, they have paradoxically provided both a predictive paper on why nations will fail in the future and a blueprint for prosperity for contemporary policy practitioners who are conversant with development theory.
In a sentence, it is those countries that establish inclusive political and economic institutions that will succeed. View the discussion thread. Books for self-isolation: Revisiting Why Nations Fail. Scott Robinson. Related Content. In Yemen, a deadly concoction of arms sales, conflict and Covid Show 2 Comments View the discussion thread. A wonderfully readable mix of history, political science, and economics, this book will change the way we think about economic development.
Why Nations Fail is a must-read book. Like me, you may succumb to reading it in one go, and then you may come back to it again and again. Without the inclusive institutions that first evolved in the West, sustainable growth is impossible, because only a truly free society can foster genuine innovation and the creative destruction that is its corollary.
The Wealth of Nations is still being read today. With the same perspicacity and with the same broad historical perspective, Daron Acemoglu and James Robinson have retackled this same question for our own times. Two centuries from now our great-great-. It explains huge swathes of human history. It is equally at home in Asia, Africa and the Americas. It is fair to left and right and every flavor in between. It illuminates the past as it gives us a new way to think about the present. It is that rare book in economics that convinces the reader that the authors want the best for ordinary people.
It will provide scholars with years of argument and ordinary readers with years of did-you-know-that dinner conversation. It has some jokes, which are always welcome. It is an excellent book and should be purchased forthwith, so to encourage the authors to keep working.
Imagine that they weave their ideas into a coherent theoretical framework based on limiting extraction, promoting creative destruction, and creating strong political institutions that share power and you begin to see the contribution of this brilliant and engagingly written book. Somehow they can generate both excitement and reflection.
From the absolutism of the Stuarts to the antebellum South, from Sierra Leone to Colombia, this magisterial work shows how powerful elites rig the rules to benefit themselves at the expense of the many. Charting a careful course between the pessimists and optimists, the authors demonstrate history and geography need not be destiny.
But they also document how sensible economic ideas and policies often achieve little in the absence of fundamental political change. Acemoglu and Robinson lay out a convincing theory of almost everything to do with economic development.
Countries rise when they put in place the right pro-growth political institutions and they fail—often spectacularly—when those institutions ossify or fail to adapt. Powerful people always and everywhere seek to grab complete control over government, undermining broader social progress for their own greed. Keep those people in check with effective democracy or watch your nation fail. The book reviews how some good regimes got launched and then had a virtuous spiral, while bad regimes remain in a vicious spiral.
This is important analysis not to be missed. Through a broad multiplicity of historical examples, they show how institutional developments, sometimes based on very accidental circumstances, have had enormous consequences.
The openness of a society, its willingness to permit creative destruction, and the rule of appear to be decisive for economic development. This highly accessible book provides welcome insight to specialists and general readers alike.
With the same perspicacity and with the same broad historical perspective, Daron Acemoglu and James Robinson have re-tackled this same question for our own times. Two centuries from now our great-great-…-great grandchildren will be, similarly, reading Why Nations Fail. Their answer is also simple — because some polities develop more inclusive political institutions.
What is remarkable about the book is the crispness and clarity of the writing, the elegance of the argument, and the remarkable richness of historical detail. This book is a must read at a moment where governments right across the western world must come up with the political will to deal with a debt crisis of unusual proportions.
More originally, they argue countries are more likely to develop the right institutions when they have an open pluralistic political system with competition for political office, a widespread electorate, and openness to new political leaders. This intimate connection between political and economic institutions is the heart of their major contribution, and has resulted in a study of great vitality on one of the crucial questions in economics and political economy.
The highly original research that Professors Acemoglu and Robinson have done, and continue to do, on how economic forces, politics and policy choices evolve together and constrain each other, and how institutions affect that evolution, is essential to understanding the successes and failures of societies and nations.
And here, in this book, these insights come in a highly accessible, indeed riveting form. Those who pick this book up and start reading will have trouble putting it down. Let tyrants everywhere tremble! Their answers are profound, lucid, and convincing. C o n t e n t s Preface Why Egyptians fi lled Tahrir Square to bring down Hosni Mubarak and what it means for our understanding of the causes of prosperity and poverty 1.
Why is one rich and one poor? The Making of Prosperity and Poverty How prosperity and poverty are determined by the incentives created by institutions, and how politics determines what institutions a nation has 4. Small Differences and Critical Junctures: The Weight of History How institutions change through political confl ict and how the past shapes the present 5.
Drifting Apart How institutions evolve over time, often slowly drifting apart 7. The Turning Point How a political revolution in changed institutions in England and led to the Industrial Revolution 8. Reversing Development How European colonialism impoverished large parts of the world The Diffusion of Prosperity How some parts of the world took different paths to prosperity from that of Britain The Virtuous Circle How institutions that encourage prosperity create positive feedback loops that prevent the efforts by elites to undermine them The Vicious Circle How institutions that create poverty generate negative feedback loops and endure Why Nations Fail Today Institutions, institutions, institutions Breaking the Mold How a few countries changed their economic trajectory by changing their institutions Understanding Prosperity and Poverty How the world could have been different and how understanding this can explain why most attempts to combat poverty have failed Acknowledgments Bibliographical Essay and Sources References Index.
Start earning points for buying books! Uplift Native American Stories. Add to Bookshelf. Read An Excerpt. Sep 17, ISBN Add to Cart. Buy from Other Retailers:. Mar 20, ISBN Audiobook Download. Paperback —.
Add to Cart Add to Cart. About Why Nations Fail Brilliant and engagingly written, Why Nations Fail answers the question that has stumped the experts for centuries: Why are some nations rich and others poor, divided by wealth and poverty, health and sickness, food and famine? Also by Daron Acemoglu , James A. See all books by Daron Acemoglu , James A. About James A. Robinson James A. Product Details. Inspired by Your Browsing History.
Economics in One Lesson. Henry Hazlitt. Ages of American Capitalism. Jonathan Levy. The New Class War. Michael Lind. The System. Robert B. The World. Richard Haass. The Storm Before the Calm.
0コメント